您在這裡

Taxation, surplus and efficiency

15 二月, 2016 - 09:58

Despite enormous public interest in taxation and its impact on the economy, it is one of the least understood areas of public policy. In this section we will show how an understanding of two fundamental tools of analysis—elasticities and economic surplus—provides powerful insights into the field of taxation.

We begin with the simplest of cases, the federal government’s goods and services tax (GST) or the provincial governments’ sales taxes (PST). These taxes combined vary by province, but we suppose that a typical rate is 13 percent. Note that this is a percentage, or ad valorem, tax, not a specific tax of so many dollars per unit traded. Figure 5.3 illustrates the supply and demand curves for some commodity. In the absence of taxes, the equilibrium E_{0} is defined by the combination (P_{0} , Q_{0}).

media/image4.png
Figure 5.3 The efficiency cost of taxation 
 

The tax shifts S to S_{t} and reduces the quantity traded from Q_{0} to Q_{t} . At Q_{t} the demand value placed on an additional unit exceeds the supply valuation by EtA. Since the tax keeps output at this lower level, the economy cannot take advantage of the additional potential surplus between Q_{t} and Q_{0}. Excess burden = deadweight loss = AE_{t}E_{0}.

A 13-percent tax is now imposed, and the new supply curve S_{t} lies 13 percent above the no-tax supply S. A tax wedge is therefore imposed between the price the consumer must pay and the price that the supplier receives. The new equilibrium is E_{t} , and the new market price is at P_{t} . The price received by the supplier is lower than that paid by the buyer by the amount of the tax wedge. The post-tax supply price is denoted by P_{ts}.

There are two burdens associated with this tax. The first is the revenue burden, the amount of tax revenue paid by the market participants and received by the government. On each of the Q_{t} units sold, the government receives the amount (P_{t}-P_{s}). Therefore, tax revenue is the amount P_{t}E_{t}AP_{ts}. As illustrated in Measures of response: elasticities, the degree to which the market price P_{t} rises above the no-tax price P_{0} depends on the supply and demand elasticities.

\mid A tax wedge is the difference between the consumer and producer prices.

\mid The revenue burden is the amount of tax revenue raised by a tax.

The second burden of the tax is called the excess burden. The concepts of consumer and producer surpluses help us comprehend this. The effect of the tax has been to reduce consumer surplus by P_{t}E_{t}E_{0}P_{0}. This is the reduction in the pre-tax surplus given by the triangle P_{0}BE_{0}. By the same reasoning, supplier surplus is reduced by the amount P_{0}E_{0}AP_{ts}; prior to the tax it was P_{0}E_{0}F. Consumers and suppliers have therefore seen a reduction in their well-being that is measured by these dollar amounts. Nonetheless, the government has additional revenues amounting to P_{t}E_{t}AP_{ts}, and this tax imposition therefore represents a transfer from the consumers and suppliers in the marketplace to the government. Ultimately, the citizens should benefit from this revenue when it is used by the government, and it is therefore not considered to be a net loss of surplus.

However, there remains a part of the surplus loss that is not transferred, the triangular area E_{t}E_{0}A. This component is called the excess burden, for the reason that it represents the component of the economic surplus that is not transferred to the government in the form of tax revenue. It is also called the deadweight loss, DWL.

\mid The excess burden, or deadweight loss, of a tax is the component of consumer and producer surpluses forming a net loss to the whole economy.

The intuition behind this concept is not difficult. At the output Q_{t} , the value placed by consumers on the last unit supplied is P_{t} (=E_{t} ), while the production cost of that last unit is P_{ts} (=A ). But the potential surplus (P_t - P_{ts}) associated with producing an additional unit cannot be realized, because the tax dictates that the production equilibrium is at Q_{t} rather than any higher output. Thus, if output could be increased from Q_{t} to Q_{0}, a surplus of value over cost would be realized on every additional unit equal to the vertical distance between the demand and supply functions D and S. Therefore, the loss associated with the tax is the area E_{t}E_{0}A.

In public policy debates, this excess burden is rarely discussed. The reason is that notions of consumer and producer surpluses are not well understood by non-economists, despite the fact that the value of lost surpluses can be very large. Numerous studies have attempted to estimate the excess burden associated with raising an additional dollar from the tax system. They rarely find that the excess burden is less than 25 percent. This is a sobering finding. It tells us that if the government wished to implement a new program by raising additional tax revenue, the benefits of the new program should be 25 percent greater than the amount expended on it!

The impact of taxes and other influences that result in an inefficient use of the economy’s resources are frequently called distortions. The examples we have developed in this chapter indicate that distortions can describe either an inefficient output being produced, as in the taxation example, or an inefficient allocation of a given output, as in the case of apartments being allocated by lottery.

\mid A distortion in resource allocation means that production is not at an efficient output, or a given output is not efficiently allocated.