You are here

Supply in the short run

15 February, 2016 - 09:58

Each firm’s plant size is fixed in the short run, so too is the number of firms in an industry. In the long run, each individual firm can change its scale of operation, and at the same time new firms can enter or existing firms can leave the industry.

\mid The short run is a period during which the number of firms and their plant sizes are fixed.

\mid The long run is a sufficiently long period of time to permit entry and exit and for firms to change their plant size.

Perfectly competitive suppliers face the choice of how much to produce at the going market price: that is, the amount that will maximize their profit. We abstract for the moment on how the price in the marketplace is determined. We shall see later in this chapter that it emerges as the value corresponding to the intersection of the supply and demand curves for the whole market – much as described in The classical marketplace – demand and supply.

The firm’s MC curve is critical in defining the optimal amount to supply at any price. In  Figure 9.1, MC is the firm’s marginal cost curve in the short run. At the price P_0 the optimal amount to supply is Q_0, the amount determined by the intersection of the MC and the demand. To see why, imagine that the producer chose to supply the quantity Q_1. Such an output would leave the opportunity for further profit untapped. By producing one additional unit, the supplier would get P_0 in additional revenue and incur a smaller additional cost in producing those units. In fact, on every unit between Q_1 and Q_0 he can make a profit, because the MR exceeds the associated cost, MC. By the same argument, it makes no sense to increase output beyond Q_0, to Q_2 for example, because the cost of such additional units of output, MC, exceeds the revenue from them. The MC therefore defines an optimal supply response.

Application Box: The law of one price

If information does not flow then prices in different parts of a market may differ and potential entrants may not know to enter a profitable market.

Consider the fishermen off the coast of Kerala, India in the late 1990s. Their market was studied by Robert Jensen, a development economist. Prior to 1997, fishermen tended to bring their fish to their home market or port. This was cheaper than venturing to other ports, particularly if there was no certainty regarding price. For the most part, prices were high in some local markets and low in others – depending upon the daily catch. Frequently fish was thrown away in low-price markets even though it might have found a favourable price in another village’s fish market.

This all changed with the advent of cell phones. Rather than head automatically to their home port, fishermen began to phone several different markets in the hope of finding a good price for their efforts. They began to form agreements with buyers before even bringing their catch to port. Economist Jensen observed a major decline in price variation between the markets that he surveyed. In effect the ‘law of one price’ came into being for sardines as a result of the introduction of cheap technology and the relatively free flow of information.

But how low can the price go before supply becomes unprofitable? To understand the supply decision further, in Figure 9.2 the firm’s AVC and ATC curves have been added to  Figure 9.1.

media/image2.png
Figure 9.2 Short-run supply for the competitive firm
 

A price below P_1 does not cover variable costs, so the firm should shut down. Between prices P_1 and P_2, the producer can cover variable, but not total, costs and there should produce in the short run if fixed costs are ‘sunk’. In the long-run the firm must close if the price does not reach P_3. Profits are made if the price exceeds P_3. The short-run supply curve is the quantity supplied at each price. It is therefore the MC curve above P_1.

First, note that any price below P_3, which corresponds to the minimum of the ATC curve, yields no profit, since it does not enable the producer to cover all of his costs. This price is therefore called the break-even price. Second, any price below P_1, which corresponds to the minimum of the AVC, does not even enable the producer to cover variable costs. What about a price such as P_2, that lies between these? The answer is that, if the supplier has already incurred some fixed costs, he should continue to produce, provided he can cover his variable cost. But in the long run he must cover all of his costs, fixed and variable. Therefore, if the price falls below P_1, he should shut down, even in the short run. This price is therefore called the shut-down price. If a price at least equal to P_3 cannot be sustained in the long run, he should leave the industry. But at a price such as P2 he can cover variable costs and therefore should continue to produce in the short run. The firm’s short-run supply curve is, therefore, that portion of the MC curve above the minimum of the AVC.

To illustrate this more concretely, let’s go back to the example of our snowboard producer, and imagine that he is producing in a perfectly competitive marketplace. How should he behave in response to different prices? Table 9.1 reproduces the data from Table 8.2.

Table 9.1 Profit maximization in the short run
Labour Output Total Revenue $ Average Variable Cost Average Total Cost $ Marginal Cost $ Total Cost $ Production Decision
L Q TR AVC ATC MC TC No production where P < min AVC
0 0          
1 15 1,050 66.7 266.7 266.7 4,000
2 40 2,800 50.0 125.0 40.0 5,000
3 70 4,900 42.9 85.7 33.3 6,000
4 110 7,700 36.4 63.6 25.0 7,000
5 145 10,150 34.5 55.2 28.6 8,000
6 175 12,250 34.3 51.4 33.3 9,000 Min AVC
7 200 14,000 35.0 50.0 40.0 10,000 Price covers AVC, not ATC
8 220 15,400 36.4 50.0 50.0 11,000 Profit where P > min ATC, and supply where P = MC
9 235 16,450 38.3 51.1 66.7 12,000
10 240 16,800 41.7 54.2 200.0 13,000

Output Price=$70; Wage=$1,000; Fixed Cost=$3,000

\mid The shut-down price corresponds to the minimum value of the AVC curve.

\mid The break-even price corresponds to the minimum of the ATC curve.

\mid The firm’s short-run supply curve is that portion of the MC curve above the minimum of the AVC.

Suppose that the price is $70. How many boards should he produce? The answer is defined by the behaviour of the MC curve. For any output less than or equal to 235, the MC is less than the price. For example, at L = 9 and Q = 235, the MC is $66.7. At this output level, he makes a profit on the marginal unit produced, because the MC is less than the revenue he gets from selling it.

But, at outputs above this, he registers a loss on the marginal units because the MC exceeds the revenue. For example, at L = 10 and Q = 240, the MC is $200. Clearly, 235 snowboards is the optimum. To produce more would generate a loss on each additional unit, because the additional cost would exceed the additional revenue. Furthermore, to produce fewer snowboards would mean not availing of the potential for profit on additional boards.

His profit is based on the difference between revenue per unit and cost per unit at this output: (P - ATC). Since the ATC for the 235 units produced by the nine workers is $51.1, his profit margin is $70 - $51.1 = $18.9 per board, and total profit is therefore 235 X $18.9 = $4441.5.

Let us establish two other key outputs and prices for the producer. First, the shut-down point is the minimum of his AVC curve. Table 9.1 tells us that the price must be at least $34.3 for him to be willing to supply any output, since that is the value of the AVC at its minimum. Second, the minimum of his ATC is at $50. Accordingly, provided the price exceeds $50, he will cover both variable and fixed costs and make a maximum profit when he chooses an output where P = MC, above P=$50. Finally we can specify the short run supply curve for Black Diamond Snowboards: it is the segment of the MC curve in Figure 8.4 above the AVC curve.

Given that we have developed the individual firm’s supply curve, the next task is to develop the industry supply curve.